TABLE OF CONTENTS

Introduction

State licensing boards are state-empowered entities that regulate myriad professions, ranging from the mundane (law) to the mystical (fortune telling).1 They control who can join, how the profession operates, and how their members are disciplined.2 With such power, and the increasing prevalence of licensing boards,3 the question arises: Who regulates these regulators? This is an especially important question because many state licensing boards are composed of active market participants;4 granting regulatory power to the same group being regulated raises the concern that the licensing board will act like a cartel—a group of competitors agreeing to limit competition.5 Although states may have important reasons, such as expertise,6 for delegating regulatory control to active members of a profession, the resulting anticompetitive concerns have led to the scrutiny of licensing boards under the federal antitrust laws.7 Not all board actions are subject to this scrutiny, but in order to be exempt from the federal antitrust laws, the licensing board’s actions must receive sufficient approval from the state.8 Thus, the concern of surreptitious, cartel-like behavior by licensing boards is potentially mitigated by the political accountability of requiring a state official to approve the board’s actions.9

State-empowered entities are immune from federal antitrust scrutiny when their actions, even overtly anticompetitive ones, represent the state acting as a sovereign.10 Recently, in North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners v Federal Trade Commission,11 the Supreme Court held that for state licensing boards with a controlling number of active market participants to be shielded by this defense, known as Parker immunity,12 they must satisfy a two-pronged inquiry: (1) Was the action taken pursuant to a clearly articulated state policy, and (2) did the state actively supervise the board’s implementation of that policy?13 If the board fails either prong, the regulation falls within the ambit of the federal antitrust laws and can be enjoined as an anticompetitive practice.14 Although the board itself may enjoy immunity from monetary damages under the Eleventh Amendment,15 the Supreme Court noted that individual board members may face liability for such antitrust violations by the board.16 This gap in immunity for individual board members is a significant concern given the potential for treble damages17 and criminal sanctions.18

The threat of personal liability for individual board members raises the concern that they may be deterred from vigorously pursuing board objectives and that talented professionals may avoid service on a licensing board altogether.19 These same concerns have animated the Court in granting immunity to public officials when they violate an individual’s constitutional or statutory rights that were not clearly established at the time of the violation.20 This defense, known as qualified immunity, has been most commonly invoked in cases arising under 42 USC § 198321 and Bivens v Six Unknown Named Agents of Federal Bureau of Narcotics,22 but it has also been recognized by circuit courts for suits arising under other statutes, including the antitrust laws.23 Due to the shared concerns of government efficiency and the common-law-like jurisprudence of both § 1983 and federal antitrust law,24 individual licensing board members should be entitled to invoke a qualified immunity defense for antitrust violations by the board. Applying qualified immunity to licensing board members would not only fill the gap in immunity between the board and its members left in North Carolina State Board,25 but it could also lead to earlier, and less costly, termination of antitrust suits against individual board members at summary judgment.26

This Comment focuses on the question whether individual state licensing board members can claim qualified immunity for antitrust violations by the board. To establish when qualified immunity would be pertinent to antitrust violations, Part I discusses the Supreme Court’s application of Parker immunity to state licensing boards. Part II then identifies the analytical framework the Court has developed for determining when private actors effectuating government objectives (like members of many state licensing boards) can claim qualified immunity. Part III briefly compares Parker and qualified immunity to demonstrate how the two doctrines can complement one another, and then it applies the Court’s analytical approach discussed in Part II to state licensing board members. Although the analysis ultimately indicates that state licensing board members do not fit neatly into the qualified immunity doctrine, this Comment identifies support for extending the defense to individual licensing board members based on historical and policy considerations.

I. Parker Immunity

The Sherman Act27 makes “[e]very contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce” illegal,28 and the Clayton Act29 enables “any person who shall be injured . . . by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws” to “recover threefold the damages . . . including a reasonable attorney’s fee.”30 This broad prohibition against anticompetitive behaviors allows private plaintiffs to combat certain collective action agreements among competitors; however, there are instances in which competitors can agree to collective action without being subject to antitrust scrutiny.31 When the state empowers a group of competitors to regulate their own industry (for example, a state licensing board comprising active market participants), such an entity may be exempt from federal antitrust scrutiny.32 This exemption is referred to as Parker immunity,33 which the Supreme Court first articulated in Parker v Brown.34 Part I.A describes how the Court has developed the test for Parker immunity. Part I.B then discusses how the Court applied that test to a state licensing board in North Carolina State Board.

A. The Test for Parker Immunity

In Parker, California’s raisin regulatory regime was attacked as a violation of the Sherman Act because it expressly limited competition.35 The California legislature had empowered a commission, composed entirely of politically appointed members, to maintain prices for agricultural commodities. This involved reviewing, adopting, and enforcing prorate marketing plans that were proposed by program committees, composed primarily of nominees chosen by private producers.36

The central antitrust issue in the case was whether the Sherman Act even applied to this type of state regulation.37 In rejecting the argument that federal antitrust laws covered such state actions, the Court relied on the Constitution’s careful balancing of the powers between the federal and state governments—dual sovereigns in the United States.38 The Court applied this federalism canon39 to the Sherman Act and found no textual support or legislative history indicating any congressional intent to impinge on state sovereignty.40 Thus, the Court interpreted the statute as simply not applying when the state is “acting as a sovereign.”41 California’s regulation satisfied this standard because the state actively engaged in reviewing, approving, and executing the raisin price-fixing program.42 In the Court’s view, this level of state involvement differed from other scenarios in which Parker immunity would not apply, such as when the state attempts to immunize an individual from antitrust scrutiny by simply authorizing the violation or declaring it lawful.43 Conversely, under the Sherman Act, when a state legislature passes laws, it is acting as a sovereign for Parker immunity purposes.44 Hence, characterizing the actions of state-empowered entities as either the state acting as sovereign (Parker immune) or the state authorizing a violation of the federal antitrust laws (not Parker immune) is not simple. However, subsequent to Parker, the Court clarified when the actions of a state-empowered entity constitute the state acting as sovereign for Parker immunity purposes.

The Court introduced the modern test for Parker immunity in California Retail Liquor Dealers Association v Midcal Aluminum, Inc45 (“Midcal”). In that case, California’s wine resale program was attacked as a violation of the Sherman Act.46 The California legislature required all wine producers and wholesalers to file price schedules with the state, which then constrained the price at which the wine could be resold to retailers.47 The state neither controlled nor reviewed the listed prices, but it did penalize licensed wine merchants that sold wine below the price schedule.48 The Court explicitly noted that such resale price maintenance agreements had been found to violate the Sherman Act when engaged in by private parties, but because the arrangements were enabled by the state, Parker immunity was implicated.49

To determine whether this resale program was entitled to Parker immunity, the Court read its precedents as establishing a two-pronged test.50 The first prong of the inquiry requires that “the challenged restraint [ ] be one clearly articulated and affirmatively expressed as state policy,”51 which includes cases in which the anticompetitive effects are the “inherent, logical, or ordinary result of the exercise of authority delegated by the state legislature.”52 The second prong requires “active[ ] supervis[ion]” by the state,53 which the Court has described as serving an evidentiary function, ensuring that the entity is pursuing government objectives and not private price-fixing arrangements.54 Applying this test in Midcal, the Court readily found the first prong to be met because the state expressly allowed and enforced the resale program.55 The second prong was more problematic because the state did not set, review, or regulate the terms or prices of the agreements, instead empowering private actors to control those terms.56 In the Court’s view, Parker immunity was not satisfied because the lack of any supervision suggested that the state was simply authorizing a violation of the federal antitrust laws, a category of state activity explicitly excluded in Parker.57

Although the holding in Midcal created a two-pronged test for Parker immunity, not all state-created entities have to meet both prongs to evade antitrust scrutiny. In Town of Hallie v City of Eau Claire,58 the Court recognized that even though municipalities are not sovereign,59 and thus not categorically immune to antitrust scrutiny, they can enjoy Parker immunity by meeting only the first prong of the Midcal test.60 The Court reasoned that municipalities are required to meet only this lower standard because they presumably act in the public’s interest, given mandatory disclosure regimes and the electoral process, unlike private actors who presumably act in their own self-interest.61 The Court also suggested that in the case of a “state agency, it is likely that active state supervision would also not be required.”62 This dicta culminated in three different approaches from the circuit courts in deciding how to treat state licensing boards.63 In North Carolina State Board, the Court helped clarify which Midcal requirements state licensing boards had to meet to enjoy Parker immunity.64

B. North Carolina State Board

The different standards of Parker immunity—requiring only a clearly articulated state policy for political subdivisions65 compared to both clear articulation and active state supervision for state-empowered private actors66 —created a challenge in determining which of the Midcal prongs to apply to state licensing boards.67 These boards, like political subdivisions, may be structured as state entities with public aims, yet, like state-empowered private actors, they are often composed of a majority of private actors with private aims. In resolving the question of which Midcal prong(s) to apply to a state licensing board, some circuits resorted to a minimal inquiry test, focusing only on the board’s formal designation by the state as an agency or a political subdivision.68 Other circuits employed a fact-intensive, multifactor test that considered how similar an entity was to a political subdivision based on its open records, structure, composition, and other factors.69 The Fourth Circuit adopted yet another test that focused exclusively on whether the relevant decision-making committee was controlled by active market participants.70 It was in the face of this circuit split that the Court granted certiorari in North Carolina State Board. The Court ultimately held that state licensing boards composed of a “controlling number of decisionmakers [who] are active market participants in the occupation the board regulates must satisfy” both prongs of the Midcal test: a clearly articulated state policy and active state supervision.71

1. State licensing boards: More like municipalities or private trade associations?

As a general matter, state licensing boards operate by limiting entry into the profession and ensuring that practitioners meet specified standards.72 For some professions, this includes setting the appropriate level of character fitness, experience, and education, going so far as to accredit only certain educational institutions.73 The board can also regulate the entry of practitioners from outside of the state or country.74 After entry into the profession, the board continues to regulate practitioners by setting professional standards and enforcing them via disciplinary proceedings, which can result in the loss of the license, monetary fines, or both.75 The board’s regulatory power is more attenuated over unlicensed practitioners, but it can still act toward these individuals in ways that implicate the federal antitrust laws.76

North Carolina established the North Carolina Dental Board of Examiners (“the Board”) to regulate dentistry, with broad authority over licensed dentists.77 It is composed of six dentists with active practices, who were elected by other licensed dentists, and two other individuals.78 The Board’s activity at issue was the issuance of cease-and-desist letters threatening criminal sanctions to nondentists providing teeth-whitening services.79 Although the Board could have promulgated teeth-whitening regulations rather than issuing cease-and-desist letters, such regulations would have had to comply with state administrative procedures and been approved by the independent North Carolina Rules Review Commission.80

In determining whether the Board’s actions enjoyed Parker immunity, the Court grappled with which prong(s) of the Midcal test the Board had to satisfy.81 The Court summarily rejected the possibility that the Board, as an agency of the state, could be ipso facto Parker immune.82 Instead, the question was whether the Board functioned more like a municipality, subject only to the clear-articulation prong, or more like a state-empowered private trade association, subject to both prongs when performing government functions.83 In the Court’s view, a licensing board composed of a controlling number of active market participants raised the same anticompetitive concerns as a state-empowered private trade association because the members intrinsically suffered from “[d]ual allegiances” between their private interests and the state’s interests.84 The Court recognized that such self-interest need not be nefarious to create structural concerns regarding anticompetitive harms unintended by the state.85 The Court contrasted state licensing boards with municipalities and other “prototypical state agencies”86 based on the lack of a public election of the Board’s members, the narrow industry the Board regulated, and the potential for a private price-fixing agenda.87 Thus, in the Court’s view, “[w]hen a State empowers a group of active market participants to decide who can participate in its market, and on what terms, the need for supervision is manifest.”88

Having ruled that the Board had to satisfy both prongs of the Midcal test, the Court easily found that the cease-and-desist letters at issue in the case were not immune from antitrust scrutiny under Parker.89 The parties did not challenge the clear-articulation requirement, so the Court assumed it was satisfied in this case.90 This is likely due to the fact that the regulation at issue granted the Board broad authority to regulate the profession of dentistry and sending cease-and-desist letters to nondentist practitioners of teeth-whitening services seems like the “inherent, logical, or ordinary result of the exercise of authority delegated by the state legislature” to the Board.91 The Board did not contend, however, that there was any active state supervision over the cease-and-desist letters, and thus, because the Board had to satisfy both prongs of the Midcal test, the Court denied it Parker immunity.92

2. Unresolved: Personal monetary liability for board members?

Although the Court held that the Board did not enjoy Parker immunity for its actions in the case,93 the Court reserved the question whether individual board members can claim other defenses to personal monetary liability for a board’s antitrust violations.94 The Court noted the concern that personal antitrust liability could dissuade professionals from joining state licensing boards.95 But the Court did not weigh this concern in determining which Midcal prongs a board had to meet for Parker immunity.96 The Court also opined that a state could simply defend or indemnify board members, or ensure Parker immunity by satisfying both prongs of the Midcal test.97 The Court did not discuss the possibility of qualified immunity for individual board members, but it did reference a qualified immunity case when discussing the possibility of professionals being deterred from government service.98 Thus, there remains an unresolved question whether state licensing board members can claim an alternative defense in an antitrust case should the Parker immunity defense prove unavailing.99

II. Qualified Immunity

Government officials that violate an individual’s constitutional or statutory rights can be immune from individual capacity suits under the defenses of absolute and qualified immunity.100 Absolute immunity is limited to a subset of government functions and constitutional roles: legislative,101 adjudicative,102 and limited executive103 functions. The defense immunizes an official from monetary damages for constitutional or statutory violations that he or she commits when acting in those particular roles.104 On the other hand, qualified immunity is a more limited, albeit more common, defense for officials who “perform[ ] discretionary functions.”105 This defense does not grant immunity to officials based on their governmental roles, but rather it immunizes officials only when they do “not violate clearly established statutory or constitutional rights of which a reasonable person would have known.”106 Part II.A provides a very brief overview of how qualified immunity emerged and how the Court has developed the doctrine. Parts II.B and II.C then discuss how the Court approaches qualified immunity for private actors performing government functions, which requires analyzing the common law before enactment of the relevant statute and the policy rationales undergirding qualified immunity.

A. Brief Overview of Qualified Immunity

The doctrine of qualified immunity has emerged, and been largely developed, in the context of § 1983 and Bivens actions.107 Under these causes of action, plaintiffs bring suits for monetary damages against individual government officials that have allegedly violated the plaintiff’s federal constitutional108 or statutory rights.109 The text of § 1983 provides for no statutory defense to monetary damages,110 but historically the common law recognized certain immunities for public officials who violated an individual’s rights.111 The Court interpreted § 1983 as implicitly incorporating these common-law defenses in Pierson v Ray.112 In that case, three police officers were sued under § 1983 for unconstitutionally arresting civil rights activists protesting segregation.113 The Court held that the defendants could claim a defense based on the common-law immunity for law enforcement agents acting pursuant to probable cause and with a good-faith reasonable belief in the constitutionality of the statute being enforced.114

The Court subsequently clarified that Pierson required both a subjective (“good faith”) and objective (“reasonable belief”) inquiry into an official’s actions to establish qualified immunity.115 But in Harlow v Fitzgerald,116 the Court replaced the hybrid inquiry with the modern objective test: an official is entitled to a qualified immunity defense if he or she did “not violate clearly established statutory or constitutional rights of which a reasonable person would have known.”117 How to determine when a right is “clearly established” is less than clear,118 but the analysis focuses on determining if a reasonable official would have known the actions at issue violated another’s rights based on existing precedent that put the question beyond debate.119

Despite the common-law justification for recognizing qualified immunity in § 1983 cases, the doctrine has been viewed as a child of modern judicial conception, and thus the courts have exercised wide discretion in raising it.120 One example is the Court’s transformation of the common-law test for immunity into the modern objective test described above. Another example is the courts’ extension of the defense to causes of action outside of § 1983; the Supreme Court has intimated that the defense may be available for other statutes,121 and it has recognized the defense for Bivens actions, a constitutional rather than a statutory cause of action.122 The circuit courts have also exercised discretion by reading the defense into a variety of different statutes.123

In addition to the expansion of the availability of qualified immunity to different types of claims, the courts have also expansively applied the defense to different categories of government officials.124 Courts have even recognized that private actors performing government functions are entitled to qualified immunity in certain circumstances.125 Specifically, private defendants effectuating government objectives are entitled to claim qualified immunity when there is a “tradition of immunity [ ] so firmly rooted in the common law and [ ] supported by such strong policy reasons” that Congress would have expressly abrogated the defense in the relevant statute if it intended to do so.126

B. “Tradition of Immunity . . . Firmly Rooted in the Common Law”

The Court first engaged the question whether private defendants could claim qualified immunity in Wyatt v Cole.127 In that case, the private defendants faced liability under § 1983 for enforcing a state replevin statute128 that was held to be an unconstitutional violation of the plaintiff’s due process rights.129 Looking to the common law, the Court identified the analogous torts as malicious prosecution and abuse of process.130 Despite identifying common-law cases that recognized a good-faith defense for private defendants against these types of torts,131 similar to the common-law defense identified in Pierson,132 the Court held this to be an insufficient “tradition of immunity.” It rejected the ability of the private defendants to claim qualified immunity because they were not furthering any discernable government interest in enforcing the replevin statute.133

The Court again denied qualified immunity to private actors in Richardson v McKnight,134 but this time the defendants were performing a substantial government function—guarding a private prison.135 Although public prison guards enjoy qualified immunity,136 the Court still denied application of the defense to the private guards based, in part, on insufficient support in the common law.137 The plaintiff claimed that the prison guards injured him by using restraints that were too tight,138 and the Court analogized this § 1983 claim to the common-law tort of prisoner mistreatment, which allowed for recovery of damages against private prison management.139 Although the Court identified a number of common-law cases holding private prison management liable for such torts, there was a dearth of case law supporting or refuting liability for private prison guards.140 Based on this lack of “conclusive evidence,” the Court found insufficient historical support for recognizing qualified immunity for the private prison guards.141 The dissent criticized the majority as requiring the defendant to identify a specific common-law case recognizing immunity for a substantially similar defendant.142 Instead, the dissent argued for a broader functional view of the common law, which generally recognized immunity for private actors performing government functions.143

Most recently, relying on a historical approach similar to the one presented by the Richardson dissent,144 the Court has unanimously recognized qualified immunity for a private attorney working part-time for the government.145 In Filarsky v Delia,146 the part-time attorney was sued under § 1983 for violating the plaintiff’s Fourth Amendment rights by demanding that the plaintiff, as a target of a city’s investigation into disability fraud, provide pertinent evidence from his home.147 The Court broadly analogized between the present violation and common-law cases against government officials performing criminal investigations, but it did not dwell on whether there was a particular common-law case in which immunity was recognized for a private attorney involved in a government investigation.148 Instead, the Court provided a historical overview of the extent to which government relied on part-time participation by private citizens prior to enactment of § 1983.149 The government was much smaller and largely limited to local institutions, eschewing a professionally staffed bureaucracy because of budgetary constraints and lack of necessity.150 Thus, government officials often had to split their time between public service and their own professional occupation in order to receive sufficient compensation.151 Even law enforcement was outsourced to private citizens at times, and during those times the common law recognized a similar immunity for private citizens as it did for public officials.152 Hence, the Court found that the extensive participation of private actors in government and the immunity at common law for those part-time government workers supported recognizing qualified immunity for the part-time government lawyer.153

The evolution of the Court’s approach to qualified immunity for private actors effectuating government objectives suggests that after analogizing between the present cause of action and the common law,154 the courts should search for particular common-law cases in which immunity was granted to similarly situated defendants.155 It also suggests that they should consider broader structural features of government around the time the relevant statute was enacted.156

C. “Supported by Such Strong Policy Reasons”

After considering whether there is common-law support for extending qualified immunity to private parties effectuating government objectives, the Court then considers the applicability of three policy concerns undergirding the doctrine of qualified immunity: (1) undue timidity of officials in exercising their discretionary duties, (2) effects on government recruiting of talented candidates, and (3) distraction from official duties by litigation.157

1. Undue timidity.

The Court has often used undue timidity on the part of government officials performing discretionary tasks as the guiding policy concern for the qualified immunity analysis.158 Because qualified immunity is intended to benefit the public by having officials perform their discretionary duties, undue timidity on the part of officials based on their fear of personal liability for mistakes made vis-à-vis that discretion would undermine the very purpose of the doctrine.159 Thus, the Court has focused the undue timidity inquiry on determining whether there are sufficient private incentives to offset fear of personal liability; if there are, then the need for qualified immunity is considered less compelling for ensuring efficient government action.160

Private incentives weighing against undue timidity and qualified immunity include the potential for personal profit and market competition. In Wyatt, the Court found undue timidity to be of minimal concern because, in enforcing the replevin statute, the defendants had no public-interest motive, only a personal incentive—money.161 Because qualified immunity was designed to benefit the public by encouraging officials to perform their discretionary duties, the justification for immunizing the private defendants was absent.162 In addition to personal incentives, the Court has also looked to whether there are market, as opposed to political, forces ensuring efficient performance of government tasks. In Richardson, the Court dismissed the undue timidity concern for private prison guards because there was putatively competition for the state prison contract.163 In the Court’s view, this competition would penalize lax enforcement of regulations due to the threat of replacement, while § 1983 liability would diminish overly aggressive enforcement.164 Additionally, unlike public prisons, the private prison system was not bound by rigid civil service salary requirements and thus could institute incentive-based pay to compete in the market.165 Because the Court found these economic incentives sufficient to offset the fear of personal liability for private prison guards, it reasoned that qualified immunity was unnecessary.166

The potential for private gains does not automatically end the inquiry into undue timidity. In Filarsky, the private attorney could have demanded higher pay for his government work to offset potential § 1983 liability, but the Court did not mention this possibility. Additionally, even though there may be market competition between attorneys for part-time government work, thereby diminishing the undue timidity concern, the Court distinguished Richardson’s market analysis as applying only when dealing with for-profit firms engaged in a substantial government administrative task with limited government supervision.167 For typical part-time workers, like the attorney in Filarsky, the Court did not view the market analysis as particularly relevant.168 The Court also expressed concern that smaller local governments would bear disproportionate privatization costs by having to pay a higher premium to offset potential liability for part-time government workers compared to well-funded political subdivisions that could afford full-time specialized professionals who enjoy free qualified immunity.169 Thus, due to the potential disparity in costs for obtaining specialized labor between different political subdivisions, and the lack of sufficient private incentives, the Court found undue timidity to be sufficiently concerning that qualified immunity was warranted.170

2. Effects on recruiting talented candidates.

The second rationale the Court considers is whether the government can recruit talented individuals for government work if qualified immunity is not available. In Richardson, the Court stated that the availability of indemnification limits this concern,171 but law enforcement officials still enjoy qualified immunity despite widespread indemnification.172 Additionally, the Court recognized that private guards could demand higher pay for their potential liability because the prison was not limited to civil-service pay requirements.173 This contrasts with the Court’s ruling in Filarsky, in which the Court found the concern of liability deterring candidates to be substantial for those with specialized knowledge or expertise, despite the ability to demand higher pay or indemnification for exposure to personal liability.174 In the Court’s view, “when there is a particular need for specialized knowledge or expertise” the government often requires outside assistance from part-time private professionals, who would be more likely to “decline public engagements if they do not receive the same immunity” as their public counterparts.175 This concern is enhanced by the possibility that the private actor could face full liability for the actions of both herself and her government counterparts.176

3. Distraction of officials by excessive litigation.

The final policy rationale the Court has considered is whether an official would be unduly distracted by litigation if qualified immunity were to be denied. In Richardson, the Court recognized this concern as being of limited utility to the qualified immunity analysis, given the expected prevalence of litigation even when qualified immunity is available.177 Additionally, the state retained important discretionary functions governing prison conditions, thereby reducing the likelihood of a lawsuit against the private prison.178 In contrast, the Filarsky Court identified the threat of distraction as a more significant concern because litigation against private actors performing part-time government work could ensnare public officials who were also working on the same project.179 In this way, public officials who are entitled to qualified immunity could still be forced into litigation, eroding the policy protections of granting those officials qualified immunity in the first place.180

* * *

The Court’s approach to determining when a private actor effectuating a government objective is entitled to qualified immunity is based on the legal fiction that, for a “tradition of immunity . . . firmly rooted in the common law and [ ] supported by [ ] strong policy reasons,” Congress would have expressly abrogated the defense in the statute if it had intended to do so.181 The inquiry into whether the defense was “firmly rooted”182 in common-law tradition involves not only identifying particularly relevant common-law cases analogous to the modern action, but also a broader conceptualization of how government operated before the statute was enacted. For the policy rationale inquiry, the Court has identified three “strong policy reasons”183 undergirding qualified immunity. The most important is the concern of undue timidity, which the Court has found to be less compelling in cases in which there are sufficient private and market incentives to offset the risk of personal liability. The Court also looks to whether recruitment of talented candidates would be impacted if qualified immunity were not available, especially when those candidates have specialized expertise. Finally, the Court probes, less forcefully, whether officials would be substantially distracted by litigation.

III. Qualified Immunity for State Licensing Board Members

State licensing boards are involved in a variety of actions that implicate federal antitrust laws,184 which raises the concern of liability for board members if the board’s actions violate those laws.185 As discussed in Part I, Parker immunity offers members a powerful defense, but it requires both that the state clearly articulate a policy of displacing competition and that it actively supervise its implementation.186 Actions taken by state licensing boards do not always meet these requirements,187 and thus there remains a question of what defenses an individual licensing board member can raise in an antitrust case.188 One potential defense is qualified immunity.189

Before addressing whether the law supports recognizing qualified immunity for individual licensing board members involved in antitrust cases, Part III.A compares Parker and qualified immunity to delineate their common features and their complementary roles. Parts III.B and III.C then apply the Court’s qualified immunity analysis presented in Part II to licensing board members by considering the common law’s treatment of licensing regimes and how the policy rationales apply to licensing boards. Both of these inquiries support recognizing the availability of a qualified immunity defense for licensing board members.

A. Relationship between Parker Immunity and Qualified Immunity

Section 1983 and the federal antitrust laws share the distinction of being unusual federal statutory regimes whose jurisprudence have been largely left to the courts, detached from a strong statutory tether.190 Neither was envisioned to apply to as broad a category of cases as they have come to cover since their enactment: § 1983 was relegated to very particular types of actions taken by state officials,191 and the Sherman Act did not reach traditional state regulations due to Congress’s limited Commerce Clause192 powers at the time.193 Both have expanded along the contours of the Constitution, with the Fourteenth Amendment providing substance to § 1983 claims194 and the Commerce Clause increasing the reach of the federal antitrust laws.195 Additionally, although neither provides for statutory defenses against monetary damages,196 the Court’s expansion of liability under these two regimes has been followed by a parallel expansion of court-crafted defenses:197 qualified and Parker immunities.

Despite the broad similarities between § 1983 and antitrust jurisprudence, the respective defenses developed by the courts have distinct purposes and functions. The Court has justified qualified immunity as a balance between the public’s interest in vindicating violations of individuals’ rights and the public’s interest in having government officials efficiently perform their discretionary duties.198 Thus, the doctrine attempts to limit costs of mistakes on the part of officials without cloaking the actions from judicial scrutiny.199 Parker immunity, on the other hand, is premised on federalism concerns:200 states are sovereigns that exert regulatory authority within their borders, and thus federal antitrust scrutiny of such regulations requires an overt expenditure of political capital by the federal government.201 Even if a state’s regulation is undoubtedly anticompetitive,202 the defense can still cloak the regulation from federal antitrust scrutiny.203 Thus, from a broad perspective, qualified immunity shields individual officials while Parker immunity shields state actions—two distinct categories arising from different goals.204 The Court’s separate treatment in North Carolina State Board of its Parker immunity analysis and its consideration of potential effects on the liability of government actors further demonstrates the distinct role the two doctrines play.205 Such differences show that qualified immunity and Parker immunity could be complementary defenses for individual licensing board members facing personal liability for antitrust violations by the board. To determine whether these private actors performing a government function would be entitled to claim qualified immunity, the analysis focuses on determining whether the common law and pertinent policy rationales support recognizing the defense for individual licensing board members.206

B. The Common-Law Tradition Regarding State Licensing Boards

When determining whether a particular category of public officials is entitled to claim qualified immunity, the Court engages in a historical analysis to determine whether similar officials were immune at common law for analogous causes of action.207 The Court’s approach in Richardson and Wyatt suggests that this analysis focuses on identifying particular cases in which immunity was granted to similarly situated defendants,208 but the Court’s approach in Filarsky supports also broadly considering how government operated before the relevant statute was enacted.209 Thus, for antitrust claims against state licensing board members, the historical inquiry entails both searching for common-law cases granting immunity to individuals working for entities that resemble modern licensing boards and broadly considering how governments approached occupational licensing before enactment of the federal antitrust laws.

1. A short history of occupational licensing.

Government regulation of occupations has deep historical antecedents, dating back at least to the Code of Hammurabi.210 Outsourcing of this regulatory control also has historical roots; in medieval England, control over trades was often vested in guilds, which determined who could participate in the trade and under what circumstances.211 By the end of the sixteenth century,212 the guilds’ regulatory control came under siege with the emergence of the common law’s antipathy toward restraints of trade and monopolies,213 predecessor doctrines to modern antitrust jurisprudence.214 The former doctrine invalidated voluntary restraints of trade, such as covenants not to compete, if they were unreasonable.215 The latter doctrine condemned involuntary guild bylaws216 and royal grants of private monopolies217 that limited entry into trades, but guild bylaws enforcing customs and government-granted monopolies to guilds continued to be allowed.218 Parliament waded into the fray with passage of the Statute of Monopolies of 1624,219 which restricted royal grants of monopoly but continued to allow for regulatory control by guilds.220 In fact, in the famous Case of Monopolies, the English courts struck down a royal grant of monopoly on playing cards,221 yet after the Statute of Monopolies was enacted, Parliament granted a similar monopoly.222 Despite the erosion of some regulatory authority of guilds, no common-law cases seem to have been brought against restraints of trade by self-regulating professional organizations.223 Additionally, third parties were often unsuccessful in recovering monetary damages from unreasonable restraints of trade, unless the restraint was maliciously designed to injure the plaintiff.224

The turbulent relationship between occupational licensing and early competition law in England sailed over to the United States with a constitutional gloss. Early common-law cases against monopolies and restraints of trade focused on the individual’s qualified right to pursue a trade, which laid the foundation for economic substantive due process arguments against government regulations in the United States.225 Despite this tension, the cases and customs predating the Sherman Act indicate a level of acceptance of state licensing regimes as important mechanisms of state government. For example, in Downer v Lent,226 the California Supreme Court summarily rejected suit against the Board of Pilot Commissioners, a licensing board, for revoking a member’s license.227 Although the board’s actions were quasi-judicial, and thus may implicate absolute, rather than qualified, immunity,228 the state court recognized broad immunity because the law relied on the discretion of officials.229 The US Supreme Court also recognized the importance of state licensing boards in Dent v West Virginia,230 holding that these types of state regulations do not unduly infringe an individual’s right to pursue “any lawful calling.”231 Following this decision, and during the period (1890 to 1910) immediately following enactment of the Sherman Act (1890) and preceding the Clayton Act (1914), there was a dramatic increase in the number of state occupational licensing regimes.232 Many of these regulatory regimes vested control of the profession in boards composed of active market participants, and neither the Constitution nor the federal antitrust laws seem to have been successfully used to challenge that delegation of authority.233

This brief foray into history demonstrates that there was tension between occupational regulation and the common-law precursors to modern antitrust law, but the law recognized such regulatory regimes as important elements of state government by the time the federal antitrust laws were enacted.

2. The historical context of occupational licensing supports extending qualified immunity.

The first step in the Court’s approach to identifying a common-law tradition of immunity is to identify the common-law actions that are analogous to the modern variant. In the case of an antitrust claim against state licensing board members, the closest common-law analogy would be the treatment of monopolies and restraints of trade.234 The Court then considers whether there are common-law cases immunizing similarly situated defendants. For licensing board members, the state court in Downer recognized immunity for similarly situated defendants, but the action at issue did not involve competition laws, making the case only tangential evidence of immunity at common law. For causes of action based on competition law (restraints of trade and monopolies), third parties were typically unable to recover monetary damages unless the plaintiff could show the defendant’s anticompetitive actions were done maliciously.235 In this way, the common law adopted a good-faith defense to third-party claims for monetary damages arising from violations of the competition laws. This good-faith defense mirrors the common-law defense identified in Pierson that was used to justify recognizing qualified immunity in the context of § 1983, indicating common-law support for extending qualified immunity to licensing board members.236

Although this Comment does not identify a particular common-law case immunizing occupational regulators for anticompetitive behavior, the Court has been willing to consider the broader historical context in determining whether there is support for recognizing a qualified immunity defense.237 Government delegation of occupational regulatory control to private associations was a historically accepted practice by the time the federal antitrust laws were enacted. Even as antitrust’s predecessor doctrines emerged in England, control over trade continued to be vested in and exercised by guilds—government-empowered organizations composed of private actors.238 In the United States, occupational regulations were similarly outsourced to state-empowered active market participants before and after the enactment of the Sherman Act, seemingly without judicial obstruction.239 Although there is historical support for distinguishing between self-regulating “learned professions” and other licensed occupations,240 the Court’s reasoning in Filarsky rejects a categorical approach to the historical analysis.241

The historical analysis of occupational licensing regimes indicates that courts rejected illegitimate delegations of monopoly power. But they also recognized the states’ prerogative in regulating professions for public health and safety and denied monetary recovery for third parties when the relevant restraint of trade was made in good faith. This common-law approach toward occupational regulation could be recreated in modern antitrust jurisprudence by recognizing qualified immunity for state licensing board members: regulations not appropriately authorized by the state (not Parker immune) could be enjoined, while monetary recovery would be limited to particular types of violations (those that failed qualified immunity).

C. Policy Rationales

After considering the common-law tradition of immunity, the Court then analyzes the policy rationales animating the qualified immunity defense.242 First, the Court looks to whether personal liability would lead to undue timidity on the part of officials performing their discretionary duties.243 Second, the Court considers whether liability would impact the talent pool of candidates looking to work for the government.244 Last, the Court analyzes the extent to which litigation would distract officials from their work.245

1. Uncertain Parker immunity raises undue timidity concerns.

Members of state licensing boards are often drawn from active market participants in the profession,246 leading to private economic incentives for zealous pursuit of anticompetitive regulations.247 This weighs against the concern that these board members would be unduly timid in the face of potential antitrust liability. As made clear in North Carolina State Board, active market participants have incentives to vigorously pursue regulation of their own market beyond the public’s interest,248 which convinced the Court to require active state supervision of the Board’s actions.249 For example, eight of the ten dentists on the Board were offering teeth-whitening services when the cease-and-desist letters at issue in the case were sent to nondentist competitors.250 “[U]sing the mechanisms of government to achieve their own ends”251 is the same concern that led the Court in Wyatt to deny qualified immunity to the private defendants in that case.252 Additionally, like the private prison in Richardson, there are external forces that incentivize licensing board members to avoid overly timid regulatory actions.253 For example, the board members in North Carolina State Board were voted into office by other licensed members of the profession.254 Thus, selecting who participates on the licensing board may be more akin to market competition than a political contest, punishing insufficient regulatory rent for the profession with replacement on the board.255 As the Court noted in North Carolina State Board, the focused regulatory control of a licensing board made it more likely to pursue private price-fixing ends than a governmental entity with broader regulatory interests, such as a municipality.256

Licensing board members have a clear conflict of interest when they regulate a profession they are still actively involved in. This is distinguishable from typical part-time government workers mentioned in Filarsky, who likely do not have an inherent conflict between their personal interests and those of the public.257 Full-time licensing board members would not reap private benefits from their pursuit of government policy during their official tenure, but a part-time member has a “[d]ual allegiance[ ]” that makes his actions suspect under the antitrust laws.258 Additionally, unlike the resource-strapped political subdivision in Filarsky, there is less of a concern that a state could not afford to pay a higher premium or provide indemnification for part-time board members.259 Because this does not raise the same magnitude of concerns for deterring privatization, and the market for regulatory control over occupational licensing seems robust, the reasoning in Filarksy supporting qualified immunity does not readily extend to active market participants serving on state licensing boards.

There are, however, strong countervailing reasons why these incentives may be insufficient for licensing board members to exercise their state-empowered discretion. The actions of a state licensing board necessarily implicate questions of anticompetitive behavior: it is, at its core, an agreement among competitors not to compete along certain dimensions.260 This is significant as it implicates the full panoply of remedies for antitrust violations if the board’s actions do not enjoy Parker immunity.261 Although the concern may be mitigated by the applicable standard of antitrust scrutiny for state licensing boards,262 members may still not be so enthusiastic in pursuing board actions that are inherently anticompetitive. Board members’ liability is not entirely dependent on their own actions—they enjoy Parker immunity only when the board’s actions have been “active[ly] supervis[ed]” by the state.263 Although board members could inquire into how the state is supervising the board’s actions, no member could be certain that the public official responsible for such an activity is actively performing her duty. This situation, in which agents can be liable for the (in)action of their principals, is unusual and highly contentious.264

Beyond the unavoidable uncertainty of actual state supervision, there is also residual uncertainty of what entities are covered by the rule in North Carolina State Board. The Court distinguished between “prototypical state agencies” and those composed of a controlling number of active market participants265 but did not define “controlling,” “active,” or “market participant.”266 These issues raise the concern of undue timidity, especially because “[a]n uncertain immunity is little better than no immunity at all,”267 indicating that despite the potential for private and market incentives, this concern weighs in favor of qualified immunity.

2. The risk of personal liability may deter professional candidates.

The possibility of facing treble antitrust damages for participating on a state licensing board may deter qualified candidates from participating in the first place.268 The Court has stated that the possibility of indemnification weighs against this concern,269 yet the Court has expanded the availability of qualified immunity despite prevalent indemnification.270 The Court also ignored the possibility of indemnification in Filarsky, calling into question the relevance of this issue (to the Court) for the qualified immunity analysis. Thus, although licensing board members may be indemnified by the state,271 this does not seem to be significant to the qualified immunity analysis.272

It is also unclear if the economic incentives for zealous pursuit of board action discussed in Part III.C.1 would induce professionals to pursue board membership given the opportunity for free riding; nonboard professionals could benefit from the anticompetitive pursuits of the board while not facing personal liability for such activities. For example, in North Carolina State Board, non-Board dentists, who had complained of competing with nondentists for teeth-whitening services, benefited from the Board’s anticompetitive elimination of the competition and did not have to worry about personal liability.273 Additionally, when public officials on a licensing board can claim immunity, the concern of facing full antitrust liability may dissuade private actors from serving on these boards.274 Beyond monetary damages, the specter of professional sanctions for antitrust violations may also deter licensing board service.275 These issues are all the more concerning for those with specialized expertise, given the Court’s acknowledgement that these types of professionals do not need to work for the government.276 There may be personal benefits from participating on a licensing board,277 but given the potential for antitrust liability anytime the board acts, talented professionals may wish to avoid the hassle of part-time board membership altogether.

3. Immunity would not likely mitigate distraction by litigation.

Qualified immunity would undoubtedly decrease the stress for individual licensing board members, but it would not likely impact the distraction of officials by affecting either the quantity or extent of antitrust litigation against the board. Every antitrust suit against a board member for a violation by the board would already ensnare public officials, either as codefendants to enjoin an anticompetitive regulation or as witnesses to establish active state supervision for Parker immunity.278 By requiring a showing of state supervision for Parker immunity, the holding in North Carolina State Board anticipates a certain level of involvement for officials in antitrust litigation.279 Although the Court noted in Filarsky that distraction of officials who qualify for immunity in § 1983 cases is a concern,280 the Court’s acceptance of such distraction in the context of antitrust litigation suggests that the concern is not as pressing in these situations. In fact, some circuit courts have refused to allow interlocutory appeal of a denial of Parker immunity, suggesting a diminished concern of prolonging litigation on such matters.281 Also, similar to the situation in Richardson, the concern of distraction is attenuated by the retention of significant duties by state officials, including reviewing, approving, and enforcing the board’s regulations.282 Such state control not only ensures Parker immunity but also limits exposure of part-time workers to liability if there is a defect in the immunity.

The availability of qualified immunity would not significantly affect the level of distraction from government work, but the Court has not given this concern much weight. There is a residual level of litigation even when qualified immunity is available as a defense, so distraction by litigation cannot itself be determinative of whether qualified immunity should be available.283 Thus, given the aforementioned concerns of undue timidity and deterring qualified candidates from state licensing board service, the policy rationales support recognizing qualified immunity for individual state licensing board members.

D. Applying Qualified Immunity to Licensing Board Members

The common-law and policy rationales support extending qualified immunity to individual licensing board members facing liability for antitrust violations by the board, but that does not answer the question whether such immunity would succeed in any particular case. It may be helpful to identify how the doctrine could apply in particular examples to illuminate both the complementary functions of qualified and Parker immunity and the limits of immunity in general.

The Fifth Circuit has already provided one example. In Affiliated Capital Corp v City of Houston,284 a mayor was sued for violating the federal antitrust laws in a cable franchising scheme.285 He could not claim Parker immunity because the city was not effectuating a clearly articulated state policy,286 but qualified immunity was still available because it was not “clearly established” at the time of the anticompetitive arrangement that a home-rule city, like the mayor’s, was not per se Parker immune.287 Thus, qualified immunity did not create an absolute bar for monetary damages based on the mayor’s role but instead shielded the official only for reasonable mistakes as to the law at the time.

As another example, the Board in North Carolina State Board failed to satisfy Parker immunity, so the Court affirmed an injunction against the Board’s actions as a violation of the federal antitrust laws.288 The result would be the same if the Board members could claim qualified immunity, but monetary damages would be barred if the members were not violating a “clearly established” right. It is arguable that the board members would not be liable in North Carolina State Board, given that at the time there was a three-way circuit split, and unclear precedent in the relevant circuit, for how licensing boards should be treated under Midcal.289 Because the Board satisfied the first Midcal prong,290 a reasonable licensing board member may not have been aware that he or she was not Parker immune, and thus could not violate a “clearly established” right by sending the cease-and-desist letters.291

A more challenging example would be the hypothetical response of North Carolina to the ruling in North Carolina State Board. If the state subsequently actively supervised the Board via enactment and enforcement of reviewing procedures for all Board activities, then the Board’s actions would be Parker immune. However, if the state created reviewing procedures, but engaged in only perfunctory supervision,292 then the Board’s actions could fail Parker immunity as not being actively supervised by the state. In such a case, the Board’s action could be enjoined if anticompetitive, but determining whether individual licensing Board members could be personally liable for the violation would require an analysis of qualified immunity. If it was reasonable for the Board members to believe that they were being supervised by the state, and thus that Parker could reasonably be assumed to apply, then they could successfully invoke qualified immunity.293 In this way, qualified immunity serves to protect reasonable mistakes made by officials exercising discretionary duties, not unreasonable ignorance of federal antitrust law’s requirements.294

The above situation applies the “clearly established” inquiry to the licensing board member’s prediction of whether Parker immunity would apply to the board’s actions. If it was “clearly established” that Parker immunity would not apply, there is still the possibility that the board member did not violate “clearly established” rights arising under the federal antitrust laws. This analysis is more complicated because there are varying levels of antitrust scrutiny applied to different types of actions and different types of organizations.295 The variation in antitrust scrutiny is significant to the “clearly established” inquiry because some actions are considered to presumptively violate the antitrust laws while others undergo a more rigorous balancing inquiry. The former approach is the per se analysis, and the latter is the rule-of-reason analysis.296 It may be that the appropriate level of antitrust scrutiny and qualified immunity’s “clearly established” inquiry collapse into a single question. A per se violation covers actions that clearly violate the antitrust laws, leading to a violation of a “clearly established” right and therefore no qualified immunity. On the other hand, a rule-of-reason violation covers a wide array of different activities that require a factually intensive balancing to know if they violate the antitrust laws; thus, these types of actions likely do not violate “clearly established” rights given the uncertainty, and qualified immunity could be available. This Comment does not attempt to address the intricacies of this issue but instead presents it as a possible avenue for future consideration.

* * *

Courts should recognize qualified immunity for individual licensing board members against claims arising under the federal antitrust laws given the strong historical underpinnings and policy support for such a defense. The common law has recognized immunity for certain licensing board activities, and occupational licensing has a rich historical pedigree as a significant tool of government regulation. The policy rationales undergirding qualified immunity also support recognizing the defense for licensing board members; undue timidity is a substantial concern given the uncertainty in accurately predicting Parker immunity, and there is a real possibility that talented professionals will eschew service on licensing boards to free ride off the anticompetitive results rather than face personal liability.

Conclusion

State licensing boards perform the important government function of regulating professions, but there is a concern that these boards can be captured by interest groups and pursue private, anticompetitive ends. The Supreme Court has attempted to address this concern by allowing antitrust scrutiny of licensing board actions when the board’s actions are either not authorized or not supervised by the state. This allows anticompetitive regulations that do not represent the state’s interests to be enjoined, but it also exposes licensing board members to personal monetary liability. In this way, qualified immunity is a tool for filling the gap between the sovereign immunity of the board and the personal liability of the board members. History supports extending the defense to licensing board members, as some actions of the boards were immunized at common law and there was general acceptance of occupational regulatory regimes as part of government by the time the federal antitrust laws were enacted. Additionally, the policy rationales undergirding qualified immunity support its extension to licensing board members. Professionals serving on licensing boards may have economic incentives to aggressively regulate the market, but these incentives are tempered by professional ethics and the danger of failing to accurately predict Parker immunity. Furthermore, personal liability would likely limit participation of talented candidates on these boards, especially for part-time members who could enjoy the benefits of the board’s actions without exposure to antitrust liability. Applying the defense to licensing board members also does not completely shield their behavior. Qualified immunity applies only when members make reasonable mistakes in exercising their state-empowered discretionary duties, similar to their public counterparts. Thus, there is a strong case to be made for extending qualified immunity to private professionals who are qualified to serve on state licensing boards.

  • 1See Aaron Edlin and Rebecca Haw, Cartels by Another Name: Should Licensed Occupations Face Antitrust Scrutiny?, 162 U Pa L Rev 1093, 1096 (2014) (identifying various professions that require licensing). See also generally Morris M. Kleiner, Licensing Occupations: Ensuring Quality or Restricting Competition? (Upjohn 2006).
  • 2See Kleiner, Licensing Occupations at 29 (cited in note 1) (describing the various powers of state licensing boards).
  • 3See Edlin and Haw, 162 U Pa L Rev at 1096 (cited in note 1) (noting an increase from 5 percent of the population requiring licensing in the 1950s to nearly 33 percent in the modern era).
  • 4See id at 1103 (finding that 90 percent of licensing boards in Florida and 93 percent in Tennessee are controlled by a majority of “license-holders active in the profession”).
  • 5See generally id (arguing that state licensing boards should be treated like cartels for purposes of antitrust scrutiny). See also Neil Katsuyama, Note, The Economics of Occupational Licensing: Applying Antitrust Economics to Distinguish between Beneficial and Anticompetitive Professional Licenses, 19 S Cal Interdisc L J 565, 569–77 (2010) (comparing the economics of anticompetitive licensing with the economics of cartels).
  • 6See North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners v Federal Trade Commission, 135 S Ct 1101, 1115 (2015) (“State laws and institutions are sustained by th[e] tradition [of professional codes of ethics] when they draw upon the expertise and commitment of professionals.”) For a discussion of the costs and benefits of having professionals regulate their own profession, see generally Jonathan Rose, Professional Regulation: The Current Controversy, 7 L & Hum Behav 103 (1983). See also Ingram Weber, Comment, The Antitrust State Action Doctrine and State Licensing Boards, 79 U Chi L Rev 737, 755–57 (2012) (discussing some of the costs and benefits of licensing regimes compared to alternatives).
  • 7See Sherman Antitrust Act, 26 Stat 209 (1890), codified as amended at 15 USC §§ 1–7 (making “[e]very contract, combination . . . or conspiracy, in restraint of trade or commerce” illegal); Clayton Act, 38 Stat 730 (1914) (providing a private right of action for violations of the antitrust laws). See also, for example, North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1117 (affirming enjoinment of a state licensing board’s anticompetitive actions).
  • 8See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1110 (noting that the antitrust laws “confer immunity on anticompetitive conduct by the States when acting in their sovereign capacity”), citing Parker v Brown, 317 US 341, 350–51 (1943).
  • 9See Town of Hallie v City of Eau Claire, 471 US 34, 45 & n 9 (1985) (stating that the political accountability of municipalities, in the form of mandatory disclosure regulations and the electoral process, weighed in favor of laxer antitrust scrutiny compared to state-empowered private actors). See also Sina Safvati, Comment, Public-Private Divide in Parker State-Action Immunity, 63 UCLA L Rev 1110, 1118–26 (2016) (arguing that the limitation of antitrust immunity for state licensing boards is premised, in part, on political accountability).
  • 10See Hoover v Ronwin, 466 US 558, 574 (1984).
  • 11135 S Ct 1101 (2015).
  • 12The defense is based on the Supreme Court’s decision in Parker v Brown, 317 US 341 (1943). The defense has also been referred to as state action immunity, but this Comment refers to the defense as Parker immunity to avoid any confusion with the doctrine of state action under the Fourteenth Amendment.
  • 13North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1110, quoting California Retail Liquor Dealers Association v Midcal Aluminum, Inc, 445 US 97, 105 (1980) (“Midcal”).
  • 14See, for example, North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1117 (affirming enjoinment of the board’s anticompetitive actions).
  • 15See Goldfarb v Virginia State Bar, 421 US 773, 792 n 22 (1975) (leaving unresolved the question whether a state agency can be immune from damages liability for antitrust violations under the Eleventh Amendment).
  • 16See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (“[T]his case . . . does not offer occasion to address the question whether agency officials, including board members, may, under some circumstances, enjoy immunity from damages liability.”) (emphasis added). This Comment does not address whether state licensing board members could be immune from monetary damages for antitrust violations by the board under an Eleventh Amendment defense. For a related discussion, see generally Susan Beth Farmer, Altering the Balance between State Sovereignty and Competition: The Impact of Seminole Tribe on the Antitrust State Action Immunity Doctrine, 23 Ohio N U L Rev 1403 (1997) (discussing the interplay between the doctrines of Parker immunity and Eleventh Amendment immunity).
  • 17See 15 USC § 15 (“[A]ny person who shall be injured . . . by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws . . . shall recover threefold the damages . . . including a reasonable attorney’s fee.”) (emphasis added).
  • 18See Community Communications Co v City of Boulder, 455 US 40, 56 (1982) (noting that municipalities and corporate entities may be susceptible to criminal and civil sanctions under the federal antitrust laws when Parker immunity is unsuccessful). This Comment does not address the question whether individual state licensing board members could face criminal sanctions for antitrust violations by the board.
  • 19See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (noting these issues as potential concerns).
  • 20See Harlow v Fitzgerald, 457 US 800, 807, 818 (1982).
  • 21See 42 USC § 1983 (authorizing suits for monetary damages when state officials violate an individual’s federal statutory or constitutional rights).
  • 22403 US 388 (1971) (authorizing suits for monetary damages when federal officials violate an individual’s Fourth Amendment rights).
  • 23See Affiliated Capital Corp v City of Houston, 735 F2d 1555, 1568–70 (5th Cir 1984) (holding that a mayor, who failed to satisfy Parker immunity, still enjoyed qualified immunity against an antitrust claim). Circuit courts permit qualified immunity to be claimed for violations of a variety of other statutes as well. See Anselmo v County of Shasta, 873 F Supp 2d 1247, 1260 n 10 (ED Cal 2012) (collecting cases). But see Hepting v AT&T Corp, 439 F Supp 2d 974, 1009 (ND Cal 2006) (rejecting qualified immunity for federal wiretap statutes based on preemption doctrine and suggesting qualified immunity should be largely limited to the § 1983/Bivens context from which it emerged).
  • 24See Margaret H. Lemos, Interpretive Methodology and Delegations to Courts: Are “Common Law Statutes” Different?, in Shyamkrishna Balganesh, ed, Intellectual Property and the Common Law 89, 89–90 (Cambridge 2013) (criticizing the pernicious tendency of commentators and courts to refer to some statutes—the most common examples being the Sherman Act and § 1983—as “common law statutes”).
  • 25See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (addressing the concerns of board member liability separately from the Parker immunity holding).
  • 26Compare Mitchell v Forsyth, 472 US 511, 530 (1985) (authorizing interlocutory appeal for denial of qualified immunity under the collateral order doctrine and considering the claim suitable for immediate resolution), with South Carolina State Board of Dentistry v Federal Trade Commission, 455 F3d 436, 441 (4th Cir 2006) (denying interlocutory appeal for denial of Parker immunity).
  • 2726 Stat 209 (1890), codified as amended at 15 USC §§ 1–7.
  • 28Sherman Act § 1, 26 Stat at 209, 15 USC § 1.
  • 2938 Stat 730 (1914).
  • 30Clayton Act § 4, 38 Stat at 731, 15 USC § 15.
  • 31See, for example, United Mine Workers of America v Pennington, 381 US 657, 669–70 (1965) (“Joint efforts to influence public officials do not violate the antitrust laws even though intended to eliminate competition.”), citing Eastern Railroad Presidents Conference v Noerr Motor Freight, Inc, 365 US 127, 138, 140 (1961).
  • 32See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114 (discussing when state agencies controlled by active participants can benefit from Parker immunity).
  • 33The defense may be better described as an interpretation of the reach of the Sherman Act rather than as an immunity. See Surgical Care Center of Hammond, LC v Hospital Service District No 1 of Tangipahoa Parish, 171 F3d 231, 234 (5th Cir 1999) (en banc) (“‘Parker immunity’ is more accurately a strict standard for locating the reach of the Sherman Act than the judicial creation of a defense to liability for its violation.”).
  • 34317 US 341, 352 (1943) (holding that the action at issue in the case was an instance of the state acting as sovereign and thus excluded from the Sherman Act’s reach).
  • 35Id at 344.
  • 36Id at 346–47.
  • 37Id at 350–52.
  • 38Parker, 317 US at 351.
  • 39For a discussion of the policy rationales supporting the federalism canon in interpreting federal statutes, see Gregory v Ashcroft, 501 US 452, 457–62 (1991) (discussing the importance of having Congress make a clear statement when disturbing the balance of power between the state and federal governments).
  • 40Parker, 317 US at 350–52. The Court may also have been reluctant at the time of Parker to strike down state economic regulations under the federal antitrust laws because the Court had just recently backed away from striking down state regulatory laws under constitutional economic substantive due process. See Paul R. Verkuil, State Action, Due Process and Antitrust: Reflections on Parker v. Brown, 75 Colum L Rev 328, 329–30 (1975) (highlighting the importance of Parker immunity in avoiding judicial encroachment on state economic regulatory affairs).
  • 41Hoover v Ronwin, 466 US 558, 574 (1984), quoting Bates v State Bar of Arizona, 433 US 350, 360 (1977).
  • 42Parker, 317 US at 352.
  • 43Id at 351, citing Northern Securities Co v United States, 193 US 197, 332, 344–47 (1904).
  • 44See Hoover, 466 US at 567–68 (noting that state legislatures enacting legislation are ipso facto immune from antitrust scrutiny). See also Bates, 433 US at 361–62 (holding that a state supreme court acting in a legislative capacity is similarly immune).
  • 45445 US 97 (1980).
  • 46Id at 99.
  • 47Id at 99–100.
  • 48Id at 100.
  • 49See Midcal, 445 US at 102–03 (holding a resale price agreement to be an invalid restraint of trade under the federal antitrust laws), citing Dr. Miles Medical Co v John D. Park & Sons Co, 220 US 373, 407 (1911).
  • 50See Midcal, 445 US at 105.
  • 51Id at 105 (quotation marks omitted), quoting City of Lafayette v Louisiana Power & Light Co, 435 US 389, 410 (1978).
  • 52Federal Trade Commission v Phoebe Putney Health System, Inc, 568 US 216, 229 (2013).
  • 53Midcal, 445 US at 105, quoting Louisiana Power & Light Co, 435 US at 410.
  • 54Town of Hallie v City of Eau Claire, 471 US 34, 46 (1985).
  • 55Midcal, 445 US at 105.
  • 56Id at 105–06.
  • 57See id at 106, citing Parker, 317 US at 351.
  • 58471 US 34 (1985).
  • 59Id at 38. See also Mt. Healthy City Board of Education v Doyle, 429 US 274, 280–81 (1977) (noting that political subdivisions are not part of the sovereign state for Eleventh Amendment immunity purposes).
  • 60Town of Hallie, 471 US at 47.
  • 61See id at 45–47 & n 9. See also North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1112–13 (distinguishing the broad electorate and regulatory interests of a municipality with the more focused price-fixing interests of private actors).
  • 62Town of Hallie, 471 US at 46 n 10.
  • 63See Alexander Volokh, The New Private-Regulation Skepticism: Due Process, Non-Delegation, and Antitrust Challenges, 37 Harv J L & Pub Pol 931, 987–89 (2014) (reviewing the three-way circuit split).
  • 64North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1113–14.
  • 65Town of Hallie, 471 US at 47.
  • 66See Midcal, 445 US at 105.
  • 67See Volokh, 37 Harv J L & Pub Pol at 985–89 (cited in note 63) (discussing the challenge, and various approaches taken, in determining when a state agency is sufficiently public to merit the laxer antitrust treatment applied to political subdivisions).
  • 68See Earles v State Board of Certified Public Accountants of Louisiana, 139 F3d 1033, 1034, 1041 (5th Cir 1998); Porter Testing Laboratory v Board of Regents for the Oklahoma Agricultural & Mechanical Colleges, 993 F2d 768, 770, 772 (10th Cir 1993); Cine 42nd Street Theater Corp v Nederlander Organization, Inc, 790 F2d 1032, 1047 (2d Cir 1986). See also North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1117–18 (Alito dissenting) (arguing that, for Parker immunity purposes, it should be sufficient that the state has labeled the Board a state agency); Volokh, 37 Harv J L & Pub Pol at 987–88 (cited in note 63) (describing this analysis as a “[c]ursory [v]iew”).
  • 69See Bankers Insurance Co v Florida Residential Property and Casualty Joint Underwriting Association, 137 F3d 1293, 1296–97 (11th Cir 1998); Hass v Oregon State Bar, 883 F2d 1453, 1455–56, 1460 (9th Cir 1989); Fuchs v Rural Electric Convenience Cooperative Inc, 858 F2d 1210, 1217–18 (7th Cir 1988); Federal Trade Commission v Monahan, 832 F2d 688, 688 (1st Cir 1987). See also Volokh, 37 Harv J L & Pub Pol at 988–89 (cited in note 63) (describing the intermediate view).
  • 70See North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners v Federal Trade Commission, 717 F3d 359, 368 (4th Cir 2013). See also Volokh, 37 Harv J L & Pub Pol at 990–92 (cited in note 63) (describing the focused approach).
  • 71North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 72See Kleiner, Licensing Occupations at 29 (cited in note 1).
  • 73Id.
  • 74Id.
  • 75Id.
  • 76See, for example, North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1107–09 (noting that the Board did not have authority over the unlicensed practice of dentistry any more than a private citizen, but the Board still acted in an anticompetitive manner).
  • 77Id at 1107.
  • 78One was a dental hygienist, and another was a “consumer” appointed by the governor. Id at 1108.
  • 79Id at 1108, 1116.
  • 80North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1108.
  • 81See id at 1110–14.
  • 82See id at 1110–11 (rejecting Parker immunity for a state agency), citing Goldfarb v Virginia State Bar, 421 US 773, 791 (1975).
  • 83See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1112–13.
  • 84Id at 1111.
  • 85See id at 1114 (“This conclusion does not question the good faith of state officers but rather is an assessment of the structural risk of market participants’ confusing their own interests with the State’s policy goals.”).
  • 86Id.
  • 87See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1113–14, citing Allied Tube & Conduit Corp v Indian Head, Inc, 486 US 492, 500 (1988).
  • 88North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 89Id at 1116.
  • 90Id at 1110 (“The parties have assumed that the clear articulation requirement is satisfied, and we do the same.”).
  • 91Phoebe Putney Health System, 568 US at 229 (describing one way of satisfying the Midcal clear-articulation requirement).
  • 92North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1116.
  • 93Id.
  • 94Id at 1115 (“[T]his case . . . does not present a claim for money damages [and therefore] does not offer occasion to address the question whether agency officials, including board members, may, under some circumstances, enjoy immunity from damages liability.”).
  • 95Id.
  • 96See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (discussing the potential for individual board member liability in a separate section, and only after the Court determined which Midcal prongs a state licensing board had to meet for Parker immunity).
  • 97Id. California has responded to the Court’s suggestion by encouraging state supervision and recognizing indemnification for licensing board members. See generally, for example, Kamala D. Harris, Opinion No 15-402, Cal Op Atty Gen (Sept 10, 2015) (available on Westlaw at 2015 WL 5927487) (discussing potential avenues for ensuring active state supervision of state licensing boards and noting that current state law likely requires indemnification of board members). Oklahoma has attempted to ensure adequate state supervision by centralizing review of board actions via executive order. See Okla Executive Order 2015-33 (2015), Okla Admin Code § 1:2015-33 (empowering the Oklahoma attorney general’s office to review all nonrule board actions). Other states seem not to have responded to the decision. See Kathleen Foote, Immune No Longer: State Professional Boards Consider Their Options, 30 Antitrust 55, 56 (2015) (noting that, at the time of the article, the only state to pass legislation in reaction to North Carolina State Board was Connecticut); E. Dylan Rivers, Regulating Regulators: Active Supervision of State Regulatory Boards in the Wake of North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners v. FTC, 90 Fla Bar J 43, 46–47 (2016) (noting the general lack of response from Florida to the decision).
  • 98North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115, citing Filarsky v Delia, 566 US 377, 390 (2012).
  • 99This is an ongoing concern as complaints filed after North Carolina State Board have included claims for monetary relief against individual board members. See, for example, Verified First Amended Complaint for Injunctive and Other Relief, Wallen v St Louis Metropolitan Taxicab Commission, Civil Action No 4:15-cv-1432 (ED Mo filed Oct 20, 2016) (available on Westlaw at 2016 WL 8736744) (seeking monetary damages); Bauer v Pennsylvania State Board of Auctioneer Examiners, 188 F Supp 3d 510, 516 (WD Pa 2016) (staying the claim for monetary relief for concurrent state proceeding but dismissing the claim for injunctive relief).
  • 100Public officials sued in their official capacity are immune under the Eleventh Amendment from private suits for monetary damages when the state is the real party in interest. See Pennhurst State School & Hospital v Halderman, 465 US 89, 100–01 & n 11 (1984) (recognizing sovereign immunity for officials when relief would run directly against the state’s treasury or administration). However, this immunity may not be available for suits against officials in their individual capacity (seeking personal monetary liability) even when the claim arises from official acts. See Hafer v Melo, 502 US 21, 30–31 (1991).
  • 101See Eastland v United States Servicemen’s Fund, 421 US 491, 501 (1975) (recognizing immunity for legislators acting in their legislative capacity based on the Speech or Debate Clause of the Constitution); Tenney v Brandhove, 341 US 367, 378–79 (1951) (recognizing absolute immunity for a § 1983 claim against members of a state legislature acting in a legislative capacity).
  • 102See Stump v Sparkman, 435 US 349, 355–56 (1978) (recognizing immunity for judges acting in adjudicative roles); Butz v Economou, 438 US 478, 512–13 (1978) (recognizing immunity for prosecutors and executive officials acting in adjudicative roles). See also Cleavinger v Saxner, 474 US 193, 199–202 (1985) (detailing the factors to consider in granting qualified or absolute immunity for administrative adjudications); Buckwalter v Nevada Board of Medical Examiners, 678 F3d 737, 740–46 (9th Cir 2012) (granting an absolute immunity defense to a state licensing board acting in an adjudicative role).
  • 103See Nixon v Fitzgerald, 457 US 731, 756 (1982) (recognizing absolute immunity for the president of the United States); Imbler v Pachtman, 424 US 409, 427 (1976) (recognizing absolute immunity for particular prosecutorial functions).
  • 104For an example of a case in which a special-function official did not receive absolute immunity for performing a nonimmunized government function, see Forrester v White, 484 US 219, 230 (1988) (allowing only a qualified immunity defense for a judge who dismissed a court employee, which is an executive, rather than judicial, function).
  • 105Harlow v Fitzgerald, 457 US 800, 807, 818 (1982) (“For executive officials in general [ ] our cases make plain that qualified immunity represents the norm.”).
  • 106Id at 818. For a discussion addressing the difficulty of determining when a right is “clearly established,” see generally Karen M. Blum, The Qualified Immunity Defense: What’s “Clearly Established” and What’s Not, 24 Touro L Rev 501 (2008).
  • 107See Scheuer v Rhodes, 416 US 232, 247 (1974) (introducing the term “qualified immunity” into the Supreme Court lexicon in a § 1983 case); Economou, 438 US at 507–08 (extending qualified immunity defense to Bivens actions).
  • 108See Monroe v Pape, 365 US 167, 172 (1961) (recognizing the availability of a suit under § 1983 against state officials violating federally guaranteed constitutional rights); Bivens v Six Unknown Named Agents of Federal Bureau of Narcotics, 403 US 388, 397 (1971) (recognizing a cause of action for monetary damages against federal officials for violations of an individual’s Fourth Amendment rights).
  • 109See Maine v Thiboutot, 448 US 1, 10–11 (1980) (recognizing a claim under § 1983 for a violation of a federal statute). For a discussion of enforcing federal statutory rights via § 1983, see generally Nick Daum, Comment, Section 1983, Statutes, and Sovereign Immunity, 112 Yale L J 353 (2002).
  • 11042 USC § 1983 (“Every person who, under color of [state law], . . . subjects . . . any . . . person . . . to the deprivation of any rights . . . shall be liable to the party injured in an action at law.”).
  • 111See Filarsky v Delia, 566 US 377, 385–89 (2012) (identifying a range of circumstances in which officials would be immunized at common law for violating another’s rights, including adjudicative and law enforcement activities).
  • 112386 US 547, 557 (1967).
  • 113Id at 548–51.
  • 114Id at 555, 557 (noting that an officer should not be mulcted when enforcing a statute “he reasonably believed to be valid”).
  • 115See Scheuer, 416 US at 247–48 (“It is the existence of reasonable grounds for the belief . . . coupled with good-faith belief, that affords a basis for qualified immunity.”). See also Wood v Strickland, 420 US 308, 321–22 (1975) (explicitly noting the objective and subjective elements of the Pierson test).
  • 116457 US 800 (1982).
  • 117Id at 815–20 (reasoning that the subjective element of the qualified immunity inquiry led to costly discovery and litigation that was incommensurate with its benefit for protecting the rights of individuals).
  • 118See generally Kit Kinports, The Supreme Court’s Quiet Expansion of Qualified Immunity, 100 Minn L Rev Headnotes 62 (2016) (criticizing the surreptitious expansion of qualified immunity through the Court’s broadening of what constitutes “reasonable” and restricting what constitutes “clearly established”).
  • 119See Ashcroft v al-Kidd, 563 US 731, 741 (2011) (noting that the law must be sufficiently clear that every reasonable official would know that he or she is violating an individual’s rights, but that there need not be “a case directly on point”).
  • 120See Economou, 438 US at 501–02 (discussing how the immunity doctrine has been viewed as largely of judicial design). See also Hepting v AT&T Corp, 439 F Supp 2d 974, 1009 (ND Cal 2006) (characterizing the emergence of the qualified immunity defense for § 1983 claims as a response to the Court’s expansion of § 1983 liability).
  • 121See Mitchell v Forsyth, 472 US 511, 535 n 13 (1985) (noting that a qualified immunity defense would have likely failed in the case because the actions “would clearly have been illegal,” without suggesting that the defense would not be available because the claim was under a statute other than § 1983).
  • 122See Economou, 438 US at 500–04 (reasoning that federal officials sued under Bivens for violations of constitutional rights should be entitled to the same qualified immunity defense as state officials sued under § 1983).
  • 123See, for example, Anselmo v County of Shasta, 873 F Supp 2d 1247, 1260 n 10 (ED Cal 2012) (collecting qualified immunity cases involving statutes other than § 1983, including the Rehabilitation Act, the Food Stamp Act, and the Racketeer Influenced and Corrupt Organizations Act); Gonzalez v Lee County Housing Authority, 161 F3d 1290, 1299–1300 & n 34 (11th Cir 1998) (recognizing a qualified immunity defense for a Fair Housing Act claim); Tapley v Collins, 211 F3d 1210, 1214 (11th Cir 2000) (recognizing a qualified immunity defense for a claim under the Electronic Communications Privacy Act). But see, for example, Hepting, 439 F Supp 2d at 1009 (rejecting a qualified immunity defense under the federal wiretap statutes as being preempted by the availability of a different statutory defense).
  • 124See Andrew W. Weis, Comment, Qualified Immunity for “Private” § 1983 Defendants after Filarsky v. Delia, 30 Ga St U L Rev 1037, 1047 n 51 (2014) (providing evidence that qualified immunity has been extended to public officials without requiring the same historical inquiry as the Court performed in Pierson for law enforcement officials).
  • 125See, for example, Filarsky, 566 US at 393–94 (holding that a private attorney working part-time for a city investigation could claim qualified immunity for a § 1983 claim arising from the investigation).
  • 126Wyatt v Cole, 504 US 158, 164 (1992) (quotation marks omitted), quoting Owen v City of Independence, 445 US 622, 637 (1980).
  • 127504 US 158 (1992).
  • 128Id at 159–60.
  • 129Id at 160 (noting that the replevin statute unconstitutionally limited the judge’s discretion to deny the initial issuance of the replevin order).
  • 130See id at 164.
  • 131Wyatt, 504 US at 164–65, citing Malley v Briggs, 475 US 335, 340–41 (1986). See also Malley, 475 US at 341 n 3 (collecting common-law cases recognizing that private citizens were liable for false complaints only when done maliciously and without probable cause); Folsom Investment Company, Inc v Moore, 681 F2d 1032, 1038 (5th Cir 1982) (providing more historical analysis of the good-faith defense for malicious prosecution charges).
  • 132Wyatt, 504 US at 165 (noting the common law’s good-faith defense for false arrests by police officers), citing Pierson, 386 US at 555–57.
  • 133Wyatt, 504 US at 168. But see id at 179–80 (Rehnquist dissenting) (noting the substantial public interest in having individuals rely on the law rather than on self-help).
  • 134521 US 399 (1997).
  • 135Id at 401–02.
  • 136Id at 405, citing Procunier v Navarette, 434 US 555, 561–62 (1978).
  • 137See Richardson, 434 US at 404–07.
  • 138Id at 401.
  • 139See id at 404–07 (identifying a number of cases in both England and the United States in which prisoners successfully sued private prison managers for mistreatment).
  • 140Id at 404–07. See also id at 414–15 (Scalia dissenting) (criticizing the majority as resting its historical analysis on the lack of a particular case recognizing immunity for private prison guards without looking to the broader immunity recognized by common law for private citizens performing government objectives).
  • 141Richardson, 521 US at 407.
  • 142Id at 414–15 (Scalia dissenting).
  • 143Id at 415–16 (Scalia dissenting).
  • 144See Filarsky, 566 US at 384 (noting that understanding the common-law protections pre–§ 1983 requires “an appreciation of the nature of government at that time”).
  • 145See id at 394–96 (Ginsburg concurring) (agreeing that the private attorney should be capable of claiming qualified immunity); id at 397–98 (Sotomayor concurring) (agreeing that the private attorney should be entitled to claim qualified immunity—but only based on a case-by-case analysis, not a general blanket immunity for part-time government workers).
  • 146566 US 377 (2012).
  • 147Id at 380–82.
  • 148See id at 384–85 (relying on a case about police officers conducting a criminal investigation to establish that qualified immunity is available for the investigative activities at issue), citing Pearson v Callahan, 55 US 223, 243–44 (2009).
  • 149Filarsky, 566 US at 384–89.
  • 150Id at 384–85.
  • 151Id. For example, a local ferryman would double as a public wharfmaster, and even the attorney general of the United States was a part-time government employee until 1853. Id at 386.
  • 152Id at 387–88 (identifying common-law cases immunizing private actors assisting the sheriff in executing a warrant).
  • 153Filarsky, 566 US at 389.
  • 154The Court often looks to the common law in both England and the United States antedating enactment of the relevant statute. See Richardson, 521 US at 404–07 (inquiring into common-law cases in both the United States and England); Wyatt, 504 US at 164 (citing reviews of case law from both the United States and England); Filarsky, 566 US at 384–89 (focusing the analysis on the United States).
  • 155See Richardson, 521 US at 404–07 (using the lack of common-law cases recognizing immunity for private prison guards to support rejecting qualified immunity in the case). See also id at 415–16 (Scalia dissenting) (criticizing the majority for focusing only on whether the defendants could identify a particular pre–§ 1983 case granting immunity to similarly situated defendants rather than considering the common law’s general recognition of immunity for private actors performing government work).
  • 156See Filarsky, 566 US at 384–89 (approaching the historical analysis by viewing the broader context of the government pre–§ 1983 rather than identifying particularly similar common-law cases granting immunity).
  • 157See id at 389–92 (reaffirming the applicability of the policy rationale analysis from Richardson).
  • 158See Richardson, 521 US at 408 (noting that immunity protects the public from “unwarranted timidity on the part of public officials by, for example, ‘encouraging the vigorous exercise of official authority’”), quoting Economou, 438 US at 506; Harlow, 457 US at 814 (recognizing the need to protect the discretionary functions of government officials); Wood, 420 US at 319 (explaining that denying immunity to school board members would lead to “intimidation” in decision-making), quoting Pierson, 386 US at 554.
  • 159See Richardson, 521 US at 408 (describing the basis of the undue timidity concern).
  • 160See id at 410 (noting that market forces provided sufficient incentives to allay undue timidity).
  • 161Wyatt, 504 US at 167–69 (noting that the public interest protecting functions of qualified immunity have minimal applicability to private actors pursuing entirely private ends).
  • 162Id.
  • 163Richardson, 521 US at 409. The contract for private prisons was renewed every three years with the possibility of the state canceling after the first year, which the majority viewed as creating a competitive market. See id at 409–10. But see id at 419–20 (Scalia dissenting) (characterizing the decision to continue with a particular private prison as political, rather than economic, because of the unlikelihood that economic factors—cost and quality—would outweigh political allegiances or friendships, especially considering that it was the public’s money being spent on the operation).
  • 164See id at 409.
  • 165See id at 410.
  • 166See id at 412.
  • 167See Filarsky, 566 US at 393 (emphasizing the narrowness of Richardson’s holding), citing Richardson, 521 US at 413.
  • 168See Filarsky, 566 US at 393.
  • 169See id at 394 (noting that New York City had sufficient resources to pay for a full-time investigator, who could enjoy qualified immunity, while the city at issue could not and had to rely on part-time assistance).
  • 170See id at 393–94.
  • 171See Richardson, 521 US at 410.
  • 172See Joanna C. Schwartz, Police Indemnification, 89 NYU L Rev 885, 913 (2014) (identifying 99.98 percent of cases against individual police officers as ultimately being paid by the government via indemnification regimes).
  • 173See Richardson, 521 US at 410 (noting that in the prison contract, the private prison can “avoid many civil-service restrictions,” thereby enabling the firm to respond to “market pressures through rewards and penalties that operate directly upon its employees”). The guards may decide not to demand indemnification protection during the hiring process, however, if they feared such a request would indicate a propensity for violating others’ federal statutory or constitutional rights.
  • 174See Filarsky, 566 US at 388–90.
  • 175Id.
  • 176See id at 391. See also id at 398 (Sotomayor concurring) (recognizing the intimidating effect of facing full liability for joint private and public work if qualified immunity were to be denied to the part-time attorney).
  • 177See Richardson, 521 US at 411–12.
  • 178See id at 411. The State’s decision not to extend sovereign immunity to the private prisons also weighed against the distraction concern because the state would have recognized the potential for suit against the private prisons and employees. See id at 412.
  • 179See Filarsky, 566 US at 391.
  • 180See id.
  • 181Wyatt, 504 US at 164 (quotation marks omitted), quoting Owen, 445 US at 637.
  • 182Wyatt, 504 US at 164 (quotation marks omitted), quoting Owen, 445 US at 637.
  • 183Wyatt, 504 US at 164 (quotation marks omitted), quoting Owen, 445 US at 637.
  • 184See generally Edlin and Haw, 162 U Pa L Rev 1093 (cited in note 1) (comparing the actions of state licensing boards to cartels—a core evil regulated by the federal antitrust laws). See also Katsuyama, Note, 19 S Cal Interdisc L J at 569–77 (cited in note 5) (comparing the actions of state licensing boards to state-sponsored cartels).
  • 185See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (noting the possibility of personal monetary liability for individual licensing board members when the board is not immune under Parker).
  • 186See id at 1110, 1114.
  • 187See, for example, id at 1116 (finding Parker immunity unavailable due to lack of state supervision of the board’s actions at issue in the case); Goldfarb v Virginia State Bar, 421 US 773, 791 (1975) (finding Parker immunity unavailable due to a lack of state oversight).
  • 188See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (leaving unresolved the question whether “board members, may, under some circumstances, enjoy immunity from damages liability”). For a discussion of defenses available to board members acting in an adjudicative role, see note 102 (discussing the absolute immunity analysis for quasi-judicial activities by agencies).
  • 189See Harlow, 457 US at 807 (recognizing qualified immunity as the more commonly available defense for public officials performing discretionary tasks).
  • 190See Lemos, Interpretive Methodology and Delegations to Courts at 89–90 (cited in note 24).
  • 191See Nancy Levit, Preemption of Section 1983 by Title VII: An Unwarranted Deprivation of Remedies, 15 Hofstra L Rev 265, 267 (1987) (noting that lack of early enforcement of § 1983 was based primarily on the limited reach of the statute, covering only officials who violated an individual’s rights by acting pursuant to affirmative state law).
  • 192US Const Art I, § 8, cl 3.
  • 193See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1118 (Alito dissenting) (discussing the limited reach of the Sherman Act to state regulations at the time of its enactment). See also generally David G. Wille, The Commerce Clause: A Time for Reevaluation, 70 Tulane L Rev 1069 (1995) (criticizing the expansion of the Commerce Clause powers as a departure from the original principles animating the clause).
  • 194See Levit, 15 Hofstra L Rev at 267 & n 11 (cited in note 191) (noting the Court’s expansion of rights protected under § 1983), citing Monroe v Pape, 365 US 167, 171 (1961).
  • 195See Midcal, 445 US at 110–11 (noting Congress intended to exercise the full extent of its Commerce Clause powers when enacting the Sherman Act); North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1118 (Alito dissenting) (describing the expansion of the Sherman Act in concert with the expanded interpretation of the Commerce Clause), quoting Hospital Building Co v Trustees of Rex Hospital, 425 US 738, 743 n 2 (1976).
  • 196See 15 USC § 15 (“Any person who shall be injured . . . by reason of anything forbidden in the antitrust laws . . . shall recover threefold the damages.”); 42 USC § 1983 (“Every person who, under color of [state law], . . . subjects . . . any . . . person . . . to the deprivation of any rights . . . secured by the Constitution and laws, shall be liable to the party injured in an action at law.”).
  • 197The limited Commerce Clause powers of Congress at the time of the federal antitrust laws’ enactment and the statutory silence regarding state officials suggest that Congress did not intend, nor indeed even consider, the antitrust laws to abrogate applicable common-law defenses for such officials. In contrast, § 1983 expressly provides for a very limited defense, which some have argued demonstrates Congress’s intent to abrogate common-law immunities. See 42 USC § 1983 (“[I]n any action brought against a judicial officer . . . injunctive relief shall not be granted unless a declaratory decree was violated or declaratory relief was unavailable.”); Pierson, 386 US at 561–63 (Douglas dissenting) (arguing that the limited exception in § 1983 and the accompanying legislative history weigh in favor of precluding immunity against monetary damages for judicial officers). In this way, there may be a stronger argument for recognizing qualified immunity in the context of the antitrust laws than in the § 1983 context.
  • 198See Butz v Economou, 438 US 478, 506 (1978); Wyatt, 504 US at 167 (noting the trade-off between compensating those injured by government officials and ensuring adequate government function).
  • 199Economou, 438 US at 506–07.
  • 200See Parker, 317 US at 350–51 (discussing the balance of sovereign powers between the states and federal government in the context of the antitrust laws).
  • 201See id at 350–51 (requiring a heightened level of congressional intent to invade the state’s domain for antitrust scrutiny to apply).
  • 202See, for example, Midcal, 445 US at 102 (noting that the regulation at issue in the case would be an illegal restraint of trade if performed by purely private actors), citing Dr. Miles Medical Co v John D. Park & Sons Co, 220 US 373, 407 (1911).
  • 203See Parker, 317 US at 350–52.
  • 204This is an overly simplistic caricature, as Parker immunity incidentally shields public officials by excluding the action from the antitrust laws altogether. But qualified immunity is not a shield for laws or actions that authorize violations of an individual’s constitutional or statutory rights.
  • 205See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (discussing potential member liability in an entirely separate section and only after the Court decided the appropriate level of antitrust scrutiny of the Board’s actions).
  • 206See Parts II.B–C (discussing the relevant case law).
  • 207See Wyatt, 504 US at 164 (comparing the case to common-law malicious prosecution); Richardson, 521 US at 405 (comparing the case to common-law mistreatment of prisoners); Filarsky, 566 US at 385–86 (comparing the case to common-law criminal investigations). The common-law tradition is not always dispositive. See, for example, Wyatt, 504 US at 165–67 (finding that policy rationales outweighed indications in the common law that private individuals had immunity for similar offenses).
  • 208See Wyatt, 504 US at 164–65 (identifying a good-faith defense for similarly situated defendants at common law); Richardson, 521 US at 415–16 (Scalia dissenting) (characterizing the majority’s reluctance to acknowledge a common-law tradition of immunity as based on the lack of a specific pre–§ 1983 case granting immunity for private guards).
  • 209See Filarsky, 566 US at 384–90 (approaching the inquiry by broadly considering how private actors historically participated in a wide range of government actions, often with the benefit of immunity).
  • 210See Kleiner, Licensing Occupations at 19 (cited in note 1) (noting the Code’s medical fee schedule).
  • 211See Thomas B. Nachbar, Monopoly, Mercantilism, and the Politics of Regulation, 91 Va L Rev 1313, 1319–22, 1366–67 (2005) (discussing the importance and legal authority of guilds in the English regulatory state). But see generally Gary Richardson, A Tale of Two Theories: Monopolies and Craft Guilds in Medieval England and Modern Imagination, 23 J Hist Econ Thought 217 (2001) (arguing that guilds did not have “monopoly” powers as the term is understood today but rather had more limited regulatory control).
  • 212Some scholars have argued that the common-law doctrines applied to monopolies and restraints were common-law innovations that had minimal support before the sixteenth century. See, for example, William L. Letwin, The English Common Law Concerning Monopolies, 21 U Chi L Rev 355, 356–62 (1954) (arguing that the common law against monopolies was largely an invention of Lord Edward Coke).
  • 213The doctrines are sometimes described as one category, with monopolies identified as one type of involuntary restraint of trade. Compare, for example, Jacob I. Corré, The Argument, Decision, and Reports of Darcy v. Allen, 45 Emory L J 1261, 1302–05 (1996) (describing the common law on monopolies in terms of restraint of trade), with Keith N. Hylton, Antitrust Law: Economic Theory and Common Law Evolution 31–37 (Cambridge 2003) (distinguishing between common-law cases involving restraints of trade and those with monopolies).
  • 214See Letwin, 21 U Chi L Rev at 356–67, 373–75 (cited in note 212) (detailing the historical development of the doctrines and their relationship to modern antitrust jurisprudence). For a discussion of the limitation of these common-law analogies for modern antitrust jurisprudence, see Thomas M. Jorde, The Seventh Amendment Right to Jury Trial of Antitrust Issues, 69 Cal L Rev 1, 55–63 (1981).
  • 215See Letwin, 21 U Chi L Rev at 373–75 (cited in note 212); Michael J. Trebilcock, The Common Law of Restraint of Trade: A Legal and Economic Analysis 8–11 (Carswell 1986); J.D. Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine 8–17 (Butterworths 1971) (describing the historical development of the common-law doctrine of restraint of trade).
  • 216“Involuntary” means a regulation that operated by law or custom rather than by private agreement or contract, which were instead considered voluntary restraints of trade. See Heydon, The Restraint of Trade Doctrine at 11–17 (cited in note 215), citing Mitchel v Reynolds, 24 Eng Rep 347 (KB 1711); Trebilcock, The Common Law of Restraint of Trade at 6–14 (cited in note 215) (distinguishing between the separate doctrines of involuntary and voluntary restraints of trade).
  • 217See Letwin, 21 U Chi L Rev at 360–64 (cited in note 212) (describing early common-law cases on monopolies).
  • 218See id at 359–62, 364, 367 (describing robust guild control, including continued grants of monopolies from Parliament, following emergence of the limitation on royally granted monopolies); Nachbar, 91 Va L Rev at 1354–56 (cited in note 211) (noting the general success of guilds in the common law for regulating trades, even after the emergence of the restraint-of-trade doctrine).
  • 21921 James 1 ch 3, § 6 (1624), reprinted in 4 Statutes of the Realm 1212, 1213 (1819).
  • 220See Harold G. Fox, Monopolies and Patents: A Study of the History and Future of the Patent Monopoly 128 & n 21 (Toronto 1947) (noting the proliferation of Parliament granted monopolies following the Statute of Monopolies); Letwin, 21 U Chi L Rev at 367 (cited in note 212) (discussing exceptions in the Statute of Monopolies for corporations and guilds).
  • 221Darcy v Allin, 74 Eng Rep 1131, 1140 (QB 1602).
  • 222Fox, Monopolies and Patents at 128 n 21 (cited in note 220).
  • 223See The Pharmaceutical Society of Great Britain v Dickson, 1970 AC 403, 436 (HL 1968) (“[T]his doctrine [ ] affecting involuntary restraints has not been applied to a profession in any reported case.”).
  • 224See Donald Dewey, The Common-Law Background of Antitrust Policy, 41 Va L Rev 759, 784–86 (1955) (noting the highly restricted third-party cause of action for contracts in unreasonable restraint of trade), citing Bohn Manufacturing Co v Hollis, 55 NW 1119, 1121 (Minn 1893).
  • 225See Mark A. Graber and Howard Gillman, 1 The Complete American Constitutionalism: Introduction and the Colonial Era 312–21 (Oxford 2015) (discussing the historical basis and reproducing the text of the relevant cases and statute); Lawrence M. Friedman, Freedom of Contract and Occupational Licensing 1890–1910: A Legal and Social Study, 53 Cal L Rev 487, 492–94 (1965) (noting the historical tension between freedom to contract and occupational licensing regimes). See also generally Steven G. Calabresi and Larissa C. Leibowitz, Monopolies and the Constitution: A History of Crony Capitalism, 36 Harv J L & Pub Pol 983 (2013) (discussing the evolving attacks against government-granted monopolies under various constitutional provisions).
  • 2266 Cal 94 (1856).
  • 227See id at 95.
  • 228For a discussion of when government officials performing adjudicative functions can claim absolute, instead of qualified, immunity, see note 102.
  • 229See Downer, 6 Cal at 95 (“Whenever, from the necessity of the case, the law is obliged to trust to the sound judgment and discretion of an officer, public policy demands that he should be protected from any consequences of an erroneous judgment.”).
  • 230129 US 114 (1889).
  • 231See id at 121–22 (recognizing “from time immemorial” the state’s prerogative in requiring licensing for professionals to protect public health and safety).
  • 232See Kleiner, Occupational Licensing at 20–21 (cited in note 1) (discussing the flourishing of state occupational licensing regimes during the period of 1890 to 1910). See also Friedman, 53 Cal L Rev at 507 (cited in note 225) (contrasting the Sherman Act’s allowance of occupational licensing associations with its prohibition of other types of associations during that time period).
  • 233See Friedman, 53 Cal L Rev at 496–97, 511–24 (cited in note 225) (discussing the growth of “friendly” licensing—regulated actors controlling regulatory bodies—and the courts’ general lack of success in limiting such licensing during the period of 1890 to 1910). One exception in which the courts were routinely willing to strike down licensing requirements was for regulations on farriers. Id at 517–20 (noting that some courts distinguished between state restrictions on “common vocations,” which were struck down, and those that touched on the health, safety, and welfare of society, which were upheld as acceptable state regulations).
  • 234For a discussion of the analogy between modern antitrust laws and early common-law treatment of monopolies and restraints of trade, see note 214 and accompanying text.
  • 235For a discussion of the limited third-party cause of action, see note 224 and accompanying text.
  • 236For a discussion of the holding in Pierson, see note 114 and accompanying text.
  • 237See text accompanying notes 146–56.
  • 238See note 218 (describing the various successes of guilds in retaining regulatory control after emergence of the common law’s antipathy toward restraints of trade).
  • 239See Friedman, 53 Cal L Rev at 496–97, 511–24 (cited in note 225) (discussing the general reluctance of the judiciary to interfere with the delegation of regulatory control to active market participants).
  • 240See Richardson, 521 US at 407 (noting that the common law recognized immunity for certain types of private defendants performing government work, including doctors and lawyers), citing Tower v Glover, 467 US 914, 921 (1984); The Pharmaceutical Society of Great Britain, 1970 AC at 436 (discussing the lack of common-law cases regarding restraints of trade by self-regulated learned professions). See also Friedman, 53 Cal L Rev at 517–20 (cited in note 225) (discussing the propensity of some courts to strike down state licensing requirements for “common vocations”); Steven B. Johnson and John B. Corgel, Antitrust Immunity and the Economics of Occupational Licensing, 20 Am Bus L J 471, 475–76 (1983) (discussing how the courts have engaged in lower antitrust scrutiny for collective actions taken by “learned professions”).
  • 241See Filarsky, 566 US at 387–89 (looking to the breadth of government action performed by private actors before enactment of § 1983 rather than only at investigative functions relevant to the case at bar).
  • 242Richardson, 521 US at 407–08.
  • 243See id at 408, citing Harlow, 457 US at 814.
  • 244Richardson, 521 US at 411, citing Wyatt, 504 at 167.
  • 245Richardson, 521 US at 411, citing Mitchell v Forsyth, 472 US 511, 526 (1985).
  • 246Edlin and Haw, 162 U Pa L Rev at 1103 (cited in note 1) (finding more than 90 percent of licensing boards in Florida and Tennessee are composed of a majority of active market participants). For a discussion of why a state may want to have active market participants on state licensing boards, see note 6.
  • 247See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1112 (discussing the concern of private incentives for active market participants acting as licensing board members).
  • 248See id at 1114 (“[T]here is no doubt that the members of such associations often have economic incentives to restrain competition.”), quoting Allied Tube & Conduit Corp v Indian Head, Inc, 486 US 492, 500 (1988).
  • 249See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114 (“When a State empowers a group of active market participants to decide who can participate in its market, and on what terms, the need for supervision is manifest.”).
  • 250Id at 1108.
  • 251Filarsky, 566 US at 392 (distinguishing the defendants in Wyatt from “individuals working for the government in pursuit of government objectives”).
  • 252See Wyatt, 504 US at 168 (noting that private actors are not principally concerned with enhancing the public good and thus are undeserving of qualified immunity). See also North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114 (noting a concern that licensing board members will “confus[e] their own interests with the State’s policy goals”).
  • 253See Richardson, 521 US at 410 (noting that market pressures provided incentives to the private prisons such that qualified immunity was not necessary for private prison guards to ensure efficient execution of government duties).
  • 254North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1108.
  • 255Even the Richardson dissent would have a difficult time finding that state licensing boards have no economic motives to violate the antitrust laws. See Richardson, 521 US at 421–22 (Scalia dissenting) (arguing that the idea that private prison guards have a profit motive to violate a prisoner’s rights is implausible and contrary to available data).
  • 256See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 257See Filarsky, 566 US at 394 (holding that part-time government workers are not precluded from claiming qualified immunity).
  • 258North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1111.
  • 259If a state licensing board had geographically limited regulatory authority, similar to a special-function government unit, members could be immunized under the Local Government Antitrust Act of 1984, Pub L No 98-544, 98 Stat 2750, codified at 15 USC §§ 34–36. See 15 USC § 34(1)(B) (defining antitrust-immunized “local government” to include “special function governmental unit[s]” like schools or sanitary districts); Local Government Antitrust Act of 1984, HR Rep No 98-965, 98th Cong, 2d Sess 20 (1984), reprinted in 1984 USCCAN 4602, 4621 (“Such a [special-function government unit] would have a geographic jurisdiction that is not contiguous with, and is generally substantially smaller than, that of the state.”).
  • 260See note 5 (discussing how state licensing boards can act like cartels by agreeing to limit competition without benefiting the public).
  • 261See Community Communications Co, Inc v City of Boulder, 455 US 40, 56 (1982) (noting that public officials may be susceptible to the full suite of antitrust remedies when Parker immunity is not available).
  • 262Sometimes the Court has applied a more lenient antitrust standard for actions taken by professional organizations compared to other private organizations. See, for example, Federal Trade Commission v Indiana Federation of Dentists, 476 US 447, 458–59 (1986) (applying a lower level of scrutiny for the collective actions of a dental trade association). See also generally Johnson and Corgel, 20 Am Bus L J 471 (cited in note 240) (discussing how the courts have required a lower antitrust scrutiny for collective actions taken by “learned professions”).
  • 263See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 264See generally, for example, Deborah Schmall, et al, Corporate Officers Beware—California Court Revives and Expands the “Responsible Corporate Officer Doctrine” and Imposes Millions in Personal Fines (Paul Hastings, Jan 2009), archived at http://perma.cc/5YL5-XTUV (discussing how the responsible-corporate-officer doctrine makes corporate officers, the agents, liable for civil fines caused by the (in)action of the corporation, their principal); Martin Petrin, Circumscribing the “Prosecutor’s Ticket to Tag the Elite”—A Critique of the Responsible Corporate Officer Doctrine, 84 Temple L Rev 283 (2012) (criticizing the expanding responsible-corporate-officer doctrine as being unsupported by tort, criminal, and corporate legal principles).
  • 265North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 266See id at 1122–23 (Alito dissenting) (criticizing the majority opinion as leaving substantial uncertainty).
  • 267Filarsky, 566 US at 392.
  • 268See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115 (identifying this issue as a potential concern for state licensing boards).
  • 269See id.
  • 270See generally Kinports, 100 Min L Rev Headnotes 62 (cited in note 118); Schwartz, 89 NYU L Rev 885 (cited in note 172).
  • 271See Harris, Cal Op Atty Gen at *15–18 (cited in note 97) (noting that California likely has a duty to indemnify and defend board members, but identifying a concern that treble antitrust damages may constitute punitive damages and thus not be covered by the relevant indemnification statute); Rivers, 90 Fla Bar J at 47 & n 54 (cited in note 97) (noting the uncertainty in Florida law regarding whether licensing board members would be indemnified for antitrust violations by the board).
  • 272See generally, for example, Mullenix v Luna, 136 S Ct 305 (2015) (granting qualified immunity to a police official without any discussion of indemnification). In this way, qualified immunity may be better viewed as a means of reducing costs for local governments rather than the individual officials. For a discussion of the consequences of having government pay for constitutional torts, see generally Daryl J. Levinson, Making Government Pay: Markets, Politics, and the Allocation of Constitutional Costs, 67 U Chi L Rev 345 (2000) (arguing that economic costs may not achieve the desired level of deterrence for political actors). But see generally Myriam E. Gilles, In Defense of Making Government Pay: The Deterrent Effect of Constitutional Tort Remedies, 35 Ga L Rev 845 (2001) (acknowledging that optimal deterrence may not be achieved, but simple deterrence could be achieved by making government pay for constitutional violations).
  • 273North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1108.
  • 274Filarsky, 566 US at 398 (Sotomayor concurring).
  • 275See generally, for example, Disciplinary Counsel v Margolis, 870 NE2d 1158 (Ohio 2007) (ordering professional sanctions against a lawyer for violations of the federal antitrust laws).
  • 276Filarsky, 566 US at 390.
  • 277Ethics and a sense of service may animate professionals electing to work on licensing boards. See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1115.
  • 278See generally, for example, Bauer v Pennsylvania State Board of Auctioneer Examiners, 188 F Supp 3d 510 (WD Pa 2016) (describing how the plaintiff sought both injunctive relief against the board’s regulation and monetary relief against individual board members).
  • 279See North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1114.
  • 280See Filarsky, 566 US at 391.
  • 281See, for example, South Carolina State Board of Dentistry v Federal Trade Commission, 455 F3d 436, 441 (4th Cir 2006); Huron Valley Hospital, Inc v City of Pontiac, 792 F2d 563, 567 (6th Cir 1986).
  • 282See, for example, North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1107–08 (describing limits on the Board’s powers).
  • 283See Richardson, 521 US at 411.
  • 284735 F2d 1555 (5th Cir 1984).
  • 285Id at 1557–59.
  • 286Id at 1569–70 (noting that only after the actions at issue in the case was it clearly established that home-rule cities were not per se Parker immune and thus could be liable under the Sherman Act), citing generally Community Communications Co, 455 US 40.
  • 287Affiliated Capital, 735 F2d at 1569 (noting the lack of “clearly established” rights due to the plurality nature of the relevant Supreme Court decision), citing generally City of Lafayette v Louisiana Power & Light Co, 435 US 389 (1978) (plurality).
  • 288North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1117. Suit was brought by the Federal Trade Commission under 15 USC § 45, but the case was treated as generally concerning federal antitrust laws. Id at 1108–09.
  • 289For a discussion of the three-way circuit split, see Part I.B. See also North Carolina State Board of Dental Examiners v Federal Trade Commission, 717 F3d 359, 368–70 (4th Cir 2013) (noting that the Fourth Circuit had previously required active state supervision by a state agency operated by market participants, but the case predated the Supreme Court cases of Midcal and Town of Hallie), citing Asheville Tobacco Board of Trade, Inc v Federal Trade Commission, 263 F2d 502, 509 (4th Cir 1959).
  • 290North Carolina State Board, 135 S Ct at 1110 (accepting the parties’ assumption that the clear-articulation requirement was satisfied).
  • 291See Town of Hallie, 471 US at 46 n 10 (suggesting state agencies, like the Board in North Carolina State Board, need satisfy only the first Midcal prong for Parker immunity).
  • 292See Federal Trade Commission v Ticor Title Insurance Company, 504 US 621, 638 (1992) (holding that the state supervision prong of Parker immunity requires more than a state simply having the ability to veto an agency’s actions).
  • 293For a discussion of how the Fifth Circuit has applied a similar analysis in the context of Parker and qualified immunity, see notes 284–87 and accompanying text.
  • 294See Economou, 438 US at 506–07 (noting that it is not unfair to require awareness of clearly established rights when performing one’s official duties).
  • 295See Christopher L. Sagers, Examples and Explanations: Antitrust 85–90 (Wolters Kluwer 2d ed 2014) (discussing the general categories of antitrust scrutiny under 15 USC § 1); Johnson and Corgel, 20 Am Bus L J at 475–76 (cited in note 240) (discussing the lower antitrust scrutiny applied to collective actions taken by “learned professions”).
  • 296See Sagers, Antitrust at 87–90 (cited in note 295) (distinguishing between the types of analysis). But see id at 93–95 (highlighting the continuum of levels of antitrust scrutiny rather than rigid categories), quoting California Dental Association v Federal Trade Commission, 526 US 726, 779–81 (1999).